Elasticity of Demand

Course Outline

Elasticity of Demand

How much does quantity demanded change when price changes? By a lot or by a little? Elasticity can help us understand this question. This video covers determinants of elasticity such as availability of substitutes, time horizon, classification of goods, nature of goods (is it a necessity or a luxury?), and the size of the purchase relative to the consumer’s budget.

Teacher Resources

Transcript

Today, we begin to discuss elasticity and its applications. This is going to take us a few lectures because the material is a little bit involved and also, I'm going to be honest, the material can be a little bit tedious. There's some formulas that we're going to have to learn how to use and memorize and so forth. However, the applications are really fascinating. Moreover, elasticity is going to come back again and again. We're going to use it when we do taxes and subsidies, we're going to use it again when we do monopoly. This is just another one of those foundational concepts that is going to pay to learn well the first time we do it. Let's get started.

 

Demand curves slope down. In other words, when the price goes up, the quantity demanded goes down, when the price goes down, the quantity demanded goes up. Pretty simple. But how much does quantity demanded change when the price changes? When the price goes down, does the quantity demanded increase by a lot or by a little? That's the concept that elasticity is going to help us to understand.

 

Here's the basic terminology. A demand curve is said to be elastic when an increase in price reduces the quantity demanded by a lot. And similarly, when a decrease in price increases the quantity demanded by a lot -- that's an elastic curve. The quantity is changing a lot in response to the price. When the same increase in price reduces the quantity demanded just a little or when the same decrease in price increases the quantity demanded just a little, then the demand curve is said to be inelastic or less elastic or not elastic. The elasticity of demand is going to be a measure of how responsive the quantity demanded is to a change in the price.

 

Here's an example. Let's start with this demand curve which we're going to see is an inelastic demand curve. Notice that when the price increases from $40 to $50 that the quantity demanded goes down by just a little, by five units from 80 units to 75 units. Now consider the following -- suppose we had a demand curve like this. This turns out to be an elastic demand curve. Notice that the same $10 increase in price now reduces the quantity demanded from 80 units to 20 units. On the elastic demand curve, the quantity demanded is much more responsive to the price than it is on the inelastic demand curve. On a demand curve where the quantity demanded is responsive to the price, that's called an elastic demand. On a demand curve when the quantity demanded isn't responsive or is less responsive to the price, that's an inelastic demand or a more inelastic demand, a less elastic demand.

 

Now you may have noticed on the previous diagrams that the inelastic curve had the higher slope. That is it was more vertical, while the elastic curve was the more horizontal curve. We haven't defined elasticity technically yet. When we do so, you'll be able to see that elasticity is not the same as slope. However, they are related.










 

For the purposes of this class, if you follow a simple rule, you're going to be fine. The rule is this -- if two linear demand or supply curves run through a common point, then at any given quantity, the curve that is flatter, more horizontal, that's the more elastic curve. So if you're going to draw two demand curves which we're going to have to do many times in this class. Let's say they run through a common point. The flatter one is the more elastic curve, that will work fine for you. What determines whether a demand curve is more or less elastic? The key determinant is the availability of substitutes. As we'll see in a minute, the more substitutes, the more elastic the curve. We can also give some more specific examples that are closely related to the number of substitutes. The time horizon -- a longer time horizon is going to make the curve more elastic. The category of product, a broad category is going to be less elastic. A specific category, more elastic. Necessities versus luxuries. Luxuries are going to be more elastic. The purchase size -- bigger purchase sizes are going to be more elastic. Now I've gone through those quickly so don't worry if you haven't followed them all right away. I'm going to go through them, now, each in turn and explain the details.

 

The availability of substitutes is really the key determinant of how elastic a demand curve is. The idea is pretty intuitive. If there's lots of substitutes for a good, then when the price of that good goes up, people are going to switch from it, the good whose price is increased, towards the substitutes. They're going to buy the substitutes instead. That means that when a good with lots of substitutes, when the price of that good goes up, the quantity demanded is going to go down a lot as people switch to the substitutes. On the other hand, if we have a good which has very few substitutes, then consumers are going to find it harder to adjust when the price has changed. In particular, if the price goes up and there are very few substitutes, consumers aren't going to be able to switch out of that good into another good. So the quantity demanded is going to remain fairly constant. It's not going to fall a lot when the good has few substitutes.

 

Let's test your understanding with some quick examples. Oil, Brazilian coffee, insulin, Bayer Aspirin. Which of these goods have an elastic demand? Which of them have an inelastic demand? Let's start with oil. Are there lots of substitutes for oil or just a few substitutes? Just a few substitutes, right? So if the price of oil goes up tomorrow, at that point do we all stop driving our cars? No, there aren't very many substitutes, at least in the short run. Few substitutes that means inelastic demand for oil. What about Brazilian coffee? Some people love Brazilian coffee but there's also Ethiopian coffee, there's Mexican coffee, there's Guatemalan coffee. Therefore, lots of substitutes, therefore elastic demand. Insulin, if you don't get it you're going to die. Not many substitutes, therefore inelastic demand.

 

What about Bayer Aspirin? If you go to Wal-Mart, you'll find Wal-Mart Aspirin. If you go to Target, there's Target Aspirin. All kinds of generic aspirins. If you understand that aspirin is aspirin, you'll understand that there are lots of substitutes. If Bayer tries to raise the price of its aspirin too much, you'll say, "Forget it. I'm going to go buy the substitutes." Therefore, elastic demand. The time horizon influences the elasticity of demand for a good. And really this is just an application of the fact that the fundamental determinant is substitutes. Immediately following a price increase, it's going to be difficult to find substitutes. Therefore, immediately following a price increase, demand is likely to be fairly inelastic, but over time consumers can adjust their behavior and they can find more substitutes.

 

For example, if the price of oil goes up, then we know that there are very few substitutes in the short run. But in the long run, what are some of the things that people would do if the price of oil stays permanently higher? We'll drive smaller cars. They'll switch to mopeds. There's a lot more mopeds driven in Europe, for example, because for decades, the price of oil has been higher in Europe due to taxes. People have adjusted. In the long run, people will even adjust how cities are designed so that more people will live in apartments closer to where they work if the price of oil stays high. If the price of oil is really low, there'll be more sprawl. People will be more willing to live far away and have a big lawn if the price of oil isn't so high. The longer the time horizon, the more the ability to adjust, the more substitutes, and thus, the more elastic the demand.

 

Another factor determining the elasticity of demand, again, based upon the fundamental question: are there lots of substitutes or just a few is what we might call the classification of the good. The broader the classification, the less likely consumers will be able to find a substitute. The narrower the classification, the more likely consumers will be able to find a substitute. We've already seen an example of this. There are more substitutes for Bayer Aspirin, a narrow classification, than there are for aspirin, a wider classification. If the price of Bayer Aspirin goes up, there are more substitutes -- the generics. If the price of all aspirin goes up, there are fewer substitutes. Of course, there are still some, like ibuprofen and acetaminophen and so forth. But the narrower the classification, the more substitutes, the more elastic the demand. Another example, the demand for food. A broad classification is less elastic than the demand for lettuce, a particular type of food, a narrow classification. Therefore the demand for lettuce would be more elastic than the demand for food.

 

The nature of the good in the consumer's mind can also affect the elasticity. In particular, whether the good is thought of as a necessity or as a luxury. Now don't take these categories as somehow being out there in the world. They are more about a person's tastes. For example, for some consumers that coffee in the morning is a necessity. Even if the price of coffee goes up by a lot, those consumers will still continue to consume about the same amount of coffee. Therefore, those consumers will have an inelastic demand. They'll have an inelastic demand for goods that they consider to be necessities. The same good in someone else's mind might be a luxury. The consumer who occasionally has a cup of coffee. If the price goes up, then they're going to be more willing to say, "Nah, I'm going to switch to tea. I'm going to switch to something else." Depending upon how consumers regard the good therefore as a necessity, more inelastic demand. As a luxury, more elastic demand.

 

The final determinant is the size of the purchase relative to a consumer's budget. If the purchase is small relative to the budget, then consumers may not even notice when the price goes up. And if they don't notice, they're not going to respond with a big change in the quantity demanded. On the other hand, if we have a product which is a large part of the budget, consumers will notice. Consumers notice when the price of automobiles goes up -- that's a big purchase. They're going to shop around a lot. They're going to try and get a big bargain when the purchase is a large fraction of their budget. On the other hand, when the price of toothpicks goes up by a lot, that's not such a big deal. Consumers probably won't even notice whether toothpicks are $0.50 or a $1. That's a 50% increase in price, but you probably don't even notice that at the store. So small item at least in the short run more inelastic. Bigger items, the bigger part of the budget, ones the consumer notices, more elastic, more price sensitive.

 

Let's summarize the determinants of the elasticity of demand. For less elastic goods, that means fewer substitutes. Short run, less time to adjust, necessities, small part of the budget. Each of these factors makes the demand curve less elastic. More elastic demand, that means more substitutes. Long run, more time to adjust. Luxuries, large part of the budget. These factors make a demand curve more elastic. If you have to, memorize these, but once you understand that elasticity means how responsive is the quantity demanded to a change in the price, then you'll be able to recreate or figure out these factors again. That's it for the elasticity of demand.

 

Next time,we're going to take a closer look at technically how do we get a number? How do we calculate the elasticity of demand? Given some facts and figures on prices and quantity demanded, how do we calculate what the elasticity really is? What's the number?

 

Subtitles

Verified Available Languages
  • English
  • Spanish
  • Chinese
  • Hindi
  • French
  • Arabic


Thanks to our awesome community of subtitle contributors, individual videos in this course might have additional languages. More info below on how to see which languages are available (and how to contribute more!).

How to turn on captions and select a language:

  1. Click the settings icon (⚙) at the bottom of the video screen.
  2. Click Subtitles/CC.
  3. Select a language.
     


 

Contribute Translations!

Join the team and help us provide world-class economics education to everyone, everywhere for free! You can also reach out to us at [email protected] for more info.


Submit subtitles

 

 

Accessibility

We aim to make our content accessible to users around the world with varying needs and circumstances.

Currently we provide:


Are we missing something? Please let us know at [email protected]

Download

Creative Commons

Creative Commons License

This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NoDerivatives 4.0 International License.
The third party material as seen in this video is subject to third party copyright and is used here pursuant
to the fair use doctrine as stipulated in Section 107 of the Copyright Act. We grant no rights and make no
warranties with regard to the third party material depicted in the video and your use of this video may
require additional clearances and licenses. We advise consulting with clearance counsel before relying
on the fair use doctrine.